Out with the dog this morning, thinking about Adam Smith's factors. My economic analysis, like Smith's, relies on a breakdown and examination of costs.
When Smith looked at the world around him, he saw a declining aristocracy, a rising business class, and the immortal laborer.
When I look, I don't see an aristocracy. Land has been pretty well distributed among businesses and working-people. But what I do see is a massive financial sector that did not exist in Smith's time.
The core concept of Arthurian economics is that the cost of interest -- the factor cost of money, to put it in terms Adam Smith might use today -- consumes so much out of wages and profits that our economy just doesn't work any more.
Some of the evidence that the factor cost of money is the problem:
1. Our massive accumulation of debt;
2. The growth of finance as a portion of GDP; and
3. The high portion of corporate profit that arises from finance.
But if the problem is that interest costs consume too much of personal and business income -- that is, if the problem is debt -- then we should be able to find additional evidence of it.
If we have a monstrous debt, then we must have done a lot of borrowing. So there must have been a lot of saving, which was loaned out to generate that debt. Thus if it is true that debt is the problem -- that the factor cost of money is the problem -- then we should expect to see an astounding level of savings.
See it, we do. This graph compares the amount of money in savings to the amount of money in circulation. The numbers come from newer and older sources that don't match perfectly. But you can see the amount of money in savings in recent years is very high by historical standards.
You can also see that saving reached a (much lower) peak just at the start of the Great Depression.
This little history of savings shows a pattern that corresponds to economic conditions. A high level of saving -- twice (that we know of) -- is associated with depression-like conditions.
The graph also confirms our simple prediction that the level of savings must be extraordinarily high to have allowed the level of debt to get so high.
Next we must try to explain our situation. What circumstances allowed the problem to arise? What process contributed to the massive accumulation of debt?
Is it concentration of income that allowed the problem to develop?
The Saez graph is a very good display of the concentration of income. This graph fascinates a lot of people.
Many people look to the concentration of income as a cause of our economic troubles. And indeed, it seems a great concentration of income would permit a great increase in savings.
But a quick comparison of these two graphs does not show much similarity. The concentration of income shown on the Saez graph is high but stable from the early 1920s to the start of World War II, drops sharply during the war, runs flat from 1943 until about 1980, and then takes off for the sky.
The graph of savings relative to money-in-circulation shows an entirely different pattern. The trend line falls from onset of Depression to end of WWII, then starts a relentless increase, interrupted only from the early 1980s to the late 1990s.
I don't see a similarity between the two graphs that would suggest a cause-and-effect relation between the concentration of income and the growth of savings. Therefore I cannot say that the concentration of income is what led to the great accumulation of savings and debt.
I can say, however, that even in conditions of absolute income equality it would be possible to accumulate too much saving and too much debt.
A Thought Experiment
Imagine a world where everybody gets paid exactly the same as everybody else, no matter what job they do or how good they are at it. Assume for a moment that such a world could exist, and that incomes are all still equal the next day, the next week, and the next year.
I like this little society of absolute equals, this Neverland, because it is easy to picture: everybody in it is
exactly like me. But even in this hypothetical world it would still be possible for debt to accumulate to an excessive degree. All it would take is for people to think the same thing that we think: that credit use is a good thing.
Oh, credit use
is a good thing, but that thought is unfinished. Credit use is a good thing
when we have too little debt. Credit use is a bad thing when we have too much debt. And, yes, credit-use is good for growth, but
too much credit-use is bad for growth. I don't like reducing things to "good" and "bad," but there it is.
So now, suppose we all get thinking that credit use is a good thing, and we all start using more credit. Well, pretty soon we start running out of money to borrow. So policymakers come up with policies to get us to save more. Problem solved.
But when we save more, we spend less. Solving one problem creates another. Demand grows less, because we're spending less. The economy slows.
But we know that credit-use is good for growth. Our economists and policymakers exhort us to go out and buy stuff to stimulate the economy, and put it on the credit card. And of course we want to do that. And we do.
Things pick up some, and policymakers see that their decisions are good. So to get the economy to grow more, they do things that encourage even more credit-use. And of course then they have to do things to encourage increased saving. And on the graph of saving relative to M1 money, the trend-line goes up.
After a generation or so we seem to notice banks becoming a more important part of our daily routine. And still we find our economy growing more slowly than we want.
And after a while our debt is so big, and our interest payments so burdensome, that they eat into our spending-money, and we have to cut back on our consumption. And interest costs in our businesses are eating into profits, so we have to raise our prices.
And after a while we had this mild but relentless inflation, and all that debt, and our living standards are not what they should be, and the world is going to hell in a handbasket, and the economy just doesn't work any more.
Thus we end up with excessive debt. But at least we're all in the same boat, right? I mean, we
are in the middle of a thought experiment where there is absolute income equality.
The moral of the story: Even in a world of absolute equality, we could end up in the same mess we are in today: a mess of excessive debt and excessive savings and relentless inflation and perpetual sluggish growth. It does not depend on the concentration of income. It depends on the reliance on credit.
And the problem, in case you missed it, is that we use dogmatic, open-ended rules of thumb in our economic thinking, rules of thumb like
printing money causes inflation and this one: "Credit use is good for growth."
Open-ended rules are rules we apply without letup. The inflation rule tells us that if there is inflation, they must be printing too much money. But the rule doesn't ever have us check to see if there is even any money left.
And the credit rule tells us that if we want the economy to grow, we need to use more credit. This rule doesn't ever have us stop to see if we've used too much credit already, if we've accumulated too much debt, if we've passed a
Laffer Limit, if we've crossed the line. The rule just tells us to use more credit.
In the Arthurian view, these two rules of thumb together created the problems in our economy. We
always restrict the quantity of money, and we
always use more credit.
After you do those things for a good long time, the economy doesn't work any more.